Essay, Research Paper: Technological Changes

Economics

Free Economics research papers were donated by our members/visitors and are presented free of charge for informational use only. The essay or term paper you are seeing on this page was not produced by our company and should not be considered a sample of our research/writing service. We are neither affiliated with the author of this essay nor responsible for its content. If you need high quality, fresh and competent research / writing done on the subject of Economics, use the professional writing service offered by our company.

The early evidence on the importance of technological changes a source of the
shifts in the relative demand for different types of labor during the 1980s came
from case studies. The Bureau of labor Statistics conducted several case studies
of the effects of changes in production processes in particular industries
(Mark, 1987). In an industry that experienced a significant change in
technology, the usual pattern was a dramatic reduction in the employment of
production workers with an increase or no change in the number of skilled
workers in that industry. More recently there have been several econometric
analyses of the effects of variables like the (appropriately lagged) rate of
investment in computers and/ or other forms of “information capital” and the
ratio of expenditures on research and development to sales on changes in the
skill composition of industries (for examples, Berman, Bound and Griliches,
1994). The results of these studies are consistent with those of the case
studies and the hypotheses that the recent technological change has shifted the
relative demand for skilled labor to the right. Changes in production techniques
have widened across the country quickly, especially the multinational firms.
Thus, if technological change is an important determinant of relative demand
shifts, one would expect to observe patterns in other industrialized countries
similar to those in the United States. Some of the recent studies report results
for a variety of old industrialized (OECD) countries that are indeed consistent
with the U.S. results (Collechia and Papaconstantinou, 1996; Machin, Ryan and
Van Reenan, 1996). These countries vary a great deal with respect to changes in
their situations with respect to trade, labor market institutions (like the
importance of trade unions), and unemployment. Obviously, the relative demand
for skilled labor in each of them is rising rapidly. In my view, it is the
fairly strong evidence in favor of the wage inequality and technological change
story. A factor that is often cited as the specific issue of the post-1980 is
the widespread adoption of computer technology throughout the economy. As
mentioned above, the rate of skilled labor has tended to be greatest in those
industries with the highest rate of investment in computers. There is also
evidence that workers who use computers on the job have, other things constant,
higher earnings than those who do not (Krueger, 1993). In my view, it is
probably too early to determine that how much of the technological change dues
to computers affect wage inequality, but we will know more about the answer to
this question in 20 years. wwwwwwwwwwwwwwwwwww Over time, the difference between
the rate of economic growth and the rate of growth of the quantity of labor
input is usually attributed to technological change. It is also roughly equal to
the growth of the average real wage rate in the economy thus providing the link
that changes in technology or productivity are closely linked over time to
growth in real wages. Since the mid-1970s, however, the average real wage rate
in the United States has grown at a very low rate. Returning to the last two
columns in Table 2, column d shows the slowdown in the growth of real wages that
started around the 1970s. By subtracting column e from column d, it can be seen
that the average real wage rate has been essentially stagnant after adjustment
for the increase in average wages expected because of the upward shift in the
educational distribution. This fact is troubling for any explanation of the rise
in income inequality that focuses on skill-biased technological change. After
all, if there was so much technological change, why didn’t it cause high
average real wage increases, rather than the historically unprecedented
stagnation of wages? An answer to this question is that the effect of
technological change on the average real wage rate depends on which kind of
change occurs. Technological change that is neutral with respect to labor
skills—that increases the efficiency of both skilled and unskilled labor by
the same proportion—will result (after the adjustment of the aggregate capital
stock has occurred) in increases in the average real wage equal to the rate at
which efficiency increases. A bout of intensive skill-biased technological
change—resulting in skilled workers becoming more efficient in jobs that they
previously performed—means that as skilled workers become more productive,
their wages rise. This also leads to a rise in the wages of unskilled workers,
since they are complementary in production. But as long as elasticity of
substitution between different types of labor, o , is greater than one, then
employers will not be able fully to substitute unskilled for the higher-wage
skilled labor. Since the wages of both types of workers rise, the average real
wage rate rises; however, because of imperfect substitutability, the
skilled-unskilled relative wage rate will also rise slightly. However, extensive
skill-biased technological change—changes in production processes such that
skilled workers are profitably employed in some jobs that unskilled workers used
to do—is a different situation. In this case, the wage of skilled workers
rises, but the wage of unskilled workers fall. The average wage in the economy
rises due to extensive skill-biased technological change, but it does not rise
very much, for the increased efficiency associated with skilled workers
performing their new jobs more efficiently than unskilled workers used to is at
least partially offset by the decrease in employment in the initially skilled
jobs and by the lower productivity of unskilled workers in the jobs that remain
for them. A particular innovation, like assembly lines, railroads, or
telecommunications, may represent different forms of technological change at
different stages of its development. The introduction of personal computers, for
example, may have increased the efficiency of skilled workers in their initial
jobs, but it is clear from the various empirical studies that it caused an
increase in the fraction of jobs normally performed by skilled workers. A lot of
research and development expenditure over the past 20 years probably went into
figuring out ways that various repetitive functions could be computerized. This
should have increased the relative demand for skilled labor, but it would not
necessarily have increased output per person-hour very much. Will Inequality
Continue to Rise? The sharp rise in earning inequality and the virtual
stagnation of the average real wage in the United States since the early 1970s
are matters of intense public concern. The weight of evidence suggests that the
principle cause is an increase in the rate of extensive skill-biased
technological change. But will this trend continue? It is possible that as
computer technology becomes better able to perform more sophisticated tasks, the
effects of technology will change direction so that unskilled workers can become
more efficient in jobs that were formerly done by today’s skilled workers. For
example, insurance agents are reportedly concerned about the implications for
their future earnings of the new ability of customers to purchase their policies
through the Internet. This would represent the reverse of extensive skill-biased
technological change; high school graduates could perform most of the necessary
labor functions with computerized purchases. If practices of this sort become
fairly widespread in the future, the relative demand for skilled labor will not
shift to the right as rapidly as rapidly as it has in the recent past and might
theoretically even shift back to the left. But while one can offer possible
examples in particular industries of the technological bias turning in favor of
unskilled workers, it would be unwise to stake too much on a movement of this
sort reversing the trend toward greater inequality. After all, the demand
function for high-skilled labor has been shifting to the right fairly
consistently for a long time. Based on the post-World War II experience in the
United States, it is highly unlikely that it will not continue to do so. The
only realistic question is whether the pace of change will be as great as it has
been during the past 25 years. It is difficult to think of policies that would
halt this technological shift—for example, imposing a large tax on
computers?—and even if such policies could be put in place, they should not
be. Thus, public policies to “do something” about earnings inequality have
focused on other proposals, like a large increase in the minimum wage,
government training programs, import restrictions, tax rate reductions for rich
old people, and so forth. While this paper is not the place for a review of
these choices, it is fair to say that most of the available options either
present potentially undesirable side effects or may work only very slowly or not
at all, or all of the above. Will the supply side of the economy adjust to
reduce the amount of inequality? There has been a fairly steady rightward shift
in the educational distribution in the United States over the past half-century.
The trends shown in Table 1 imply that the relative supply of college/high
school equivalent labor has grown at an average annual rate of 2.9 percent.
Further, one might suppose that the huge increase in the private rate of return
to investment in a college education associated with the rise in the
college/high school relative would cause a large increase in the relative supply
of college graduates, which could eventually reduce the wage premium of
high-skilled labor. This is the story implicit in Figure 1, in which the
vertical short-run relative supply function shifts over time the same amount as
the relative demand function so that, in the long run, Returns to R. If this
story were correct, the rise in inequality would be a relatively temporary
event—that is, lasting perhaps another decade or two—which might not require
policy intervention. There is some supply adjustment in the pipeline, judging
from the time series data on the educational attainment of young adults and of
the proportion of college-age persons enrolled in school. For example, the
proportion of 20-to 21-year-old males enrolled in school rose from 31.6 percent
in 1979 to 42.6 percent in 1993, while the value of R increased by 17.7 percent.
The implied relative supply elasticity is 1.7, which is in line with previous
estimates of this parameter (Freeman, 1986). This value, however, is not nearly
large enough to yield the 3 to 5 percent rates of growth of relative
supply—depending on whether the next 15 years is like the 1950-1980 or the
post-1980 period—necessary to keep up with the likely technologically induced
shifts in future demand for high-skilled labor. In addition, much of the past
high rates of increase in the relative supply of educated labor were due to the
replacement of old people with a low average level of schooling by young persons
with a high average level. Beginning around 2010, the average level of education
of labor force exiters will be quite high, reflection in part the large boost in
the number of students who attended college in the 1960s, probably in part
because it was a way to defer military service. For the relative supply of
educated labor to grow rapidly after 2010, rates of college attendance will have
to be extremely large to avoid a new bout of wage inequality. It would seem,
therefore, that a long-term commitment to increasing greatly the fraction of
individuals who go to college is the appropriate public policy response to the
phenomenon of increasing inequality. But this is more easily written than done
effectively.
0
0
Good or bad? How would you rate this essay?
Help other users to find the good and worthy free term papers and trash the bad ones.
Like this term paper? Vote & Promote so that others can find it

Get a Custom Paper on Economics:

Free papers will not meet the guidelines of your specific project. If you need a custom essay on Economics: , we can write you a high quality authentic essay. While free essays can be traced by Turnitin (plagiarism detection program), our custom written papers will pass any plagiarism test, guaranteed. Our writing service will save you time and grade.




Related essays:

0
0
The purpose of this research paper is to prove that technology has been good for the stock market. Thanks to technology, there are now more traders than ever because of the ease of trading online with...
3278 views
0 comments
0
0
Economics / Theory Of Capital
This essay is an explanation and importance of complementarity and substitution in the theory of capital. Complementarity can be usually seen in goods with “sympathetic shifts in demand.” It is als...
2652 views
0 comments
0
0
Economics / Trade Unions
“A trade union is an independant self-regulating organization of workers created to protect and advance the interests of its members through collective action.” Over recent years, it has become fashio...
3209 views
0 comments
0
0
Economics / UK Welfare State
Good health is an important factor to an individual’s welfare. It is an essential prerequisite for the enjoyment of life. For this reason the importance of healthcare to governments is great and vast ...
2630 views
0 comments
0
0
Economics / US China Relations
After rather lengthy negotiations between the United States and China, there has been a trade agreement reached between the two countries. China has agreed to enter into the World Trade Organization (...
2699 views
0 comments